Spaces available for democratic expression need
to be utilised with renewed creativity by those fighting for a more
equal, less exploitative social order. There is a need to guard against
both the despair of rejecting all civil society efforts as sham as well
as of taking this democracy for granted. Can civil society organisations
work for social transformation without veering towards these two
extremes?
Establishing a democracy in a country with such massive poverty and
profound social, economic and regional inequality has been an enormous
challenge. As evidence of intensifying market and government failure
accumulated in recent decades, civil society began playing an
increasingly important role in India. This article seeks to answer the
following questions.
Can civil society be seen as an agent of social transformation in
India today? In what form and under what circumstances can the answer to
this question be given in the affirmative? In order to answer these
questions, this article attempts to: (1) Enunciate a theoretical
framework within which we can understand the role of civil society and
(2) carefully differentiate empirically the different strands within
civil society in India today.
Theoretical Framework
The most important contemporary contribution to developing a
conceptual framework for understanding civil society in India has been
that of Partha Chatterjee. He speaks of civil society in
contra-distinction to what he terms political society. Chatterjee
distinguishes between:
a domain of properly constituted civil society and a more ill-defined
and contingently activated domain of political society. Civil society in
India today, peopled largely by the urban middle classes, is the sphere
that seeks to be congruent with the normative models of bourgeois civil
society and represents the domain of capitalist hegemony. But there is
the other domain of political society which includes large sections of
the rural population and the urban poor. These people do, of course,
have the formal status of citizens and can exercise their franchise as
an instrument of political bargaining. But they do not relate to the
organs of the state in the same way that the middle classes do, nor do
governmental agencies treat them as proper citizens belonging to civil
society. Those in political society make their claims on government, and
in turn are governed, not within the framework of stable
constitutionally defined rights and laws, but rather through temporary,
contextual and unstable arrangements arrived at through direct political
negotiations…the bulk of the population in India lives outside the
orderly zones of proper civil society.
Chatterjee believes that those belonging to what he calls political
society, lacking an agency of their own, typically mobilise through
powerful patrons and brokers. While some instances of this can be found,
in the main, Chatterjee’s distinction does not appear to be of much
value in understanding the dynamics of Indian society today. Chatterjee
completely fails to see the massive mobilisation of marginalised
sections, dalits, adivasis, women and the poor, which has happened very
much “within the framework of stable constitutionally defined rights and
laws” (ibid). Especially in the past decade, we have seen the enactment
of the Mahatma Gandhi National Rural Employment Guarantee Act
(MGNREGA), the Forest Rights Act (FRA) and most recently the Andhra
Pradesh Scheduled Castes Sub-Plan and Tribal Sub-Plan (Planning,
Allocation and Utilisation of Financial Resources) Act 2013, all of
which are directed at the most marginalised sections of Indian society.
1
This is a new form of subaltern politics that increasingly
characterises India today. We have also seen the rise of powerful
adivasi women’s self-help group (SHG) federations, which are playing an
increasingly important role in mobilising the voice of the poor as
participants in extremely unfair and unequal, often oppressive markets.
So we have a very new phenomenon of the disadvantaged segments of Indian
society attempting to leverage spaces within the state to foster their
own interests.
We will return to these themes in the second part of the article. We
first need to complete the theoretical task that we set ourselves at the
beginning. Here, we must recognise that our question has to be posed in
the context of capitalist democracies, one of which is India today. For
it is in this unique space and within this unique challenge, of a
democracy which seeks to establish itself within a capitalist economy,
that we must locate our inquiry. The logical starting point for us then
has to be Hegel’s
Philosophy of Right, which was later built upon
by de Tocqueville and Marx, albeit in two quite different directions.
Having scanned the vast theoretical literature on civil society, we
believe the most useful point of departure remains the way Antonio
Gramsci built upon and transformed the Hegel-Marx framework in his
celebrated
Prison Notebooks. Ironically, our starting point is
the distinction Gramsci makes between political society and civil
society, which as we will see in a moment, is completely different from
the twist Chatterjee gives to what Gramsci had originally proposed.
According to Gramsci, in a capitalist class society, dominance is
maintained through a combination of strategies. On the one hand, there
is political society, which is that part of the state where sheer force
is deployed. But the other part of the state is civil society, where
domination is legitimised and hegemony is exercised through the
manufacturing of consent. In the First Notebook, Gramsci describes this
as “government by consent of the governed, but an organised consent, not
the vague and generic kind which is declared at the time of elections”
(Gramsci 1992: 153). Political society refers to “the armed forces,
police, law courts and prisons, together with all the administrative
departments concerning taxation, finance, etc” (Simon 1990: 71). The
role of political society, the “apparatus of state coercive power”, is
to enforce “discipline on those groups who do not ‘consent’” (Gramsci
2003: 12). But this apparatus comes into play only when the effort at
establishing legitimacy fails.
Establishing legitimacy is the domain of civil society. Instruments
of legitimation and hegemony include social institutions of civil
society: the church, the educational system, the media or to put it in
the words of Gramsci’s Sixth Notebook “the ethical content of the state”
(Gramsci 2007a: 20). Gramsci was, however, not merely concerned with
the engendering of consent and the exercise of hegemony. He was much
more interested in modes in which hegemony could be challenged. He
called this “counter-hegemony”. In his Seventh Notebook, Gramsci clearly
distinguished two ways of challenging hegemony – a “war of maneuver” or
“frontal war”, which is different from a “war of position” (Gramsci
2007b: 168). In the Sixth Notebook, Gramsci expresses the view that the
“transition from the war of maneuver to the war of position is the most
important postwar problem of political theory” (Gramsci 2007a: 109). A
war of manoeuvre involves physical overthrow of the coercive apparatus
of the state. But Gramsci realised that in modern liberal democracies,
direct confrontation through an armed uprising or a general strike will
not threaten the dominant groups so long as their credibility and
authority remains firmly rooted in civil society. As the leading Gramsci
scholar of our time Joseph Buttigieg (2005:43) puts it,
What makes the modern liberal democratic State robust and resilient, in
Gramsci’s view, is not the power of coercion that it can exercise
through political society (the legislature, the executive, the
judiciary, the police, etc) but, rather, the myriad ways in which the
core elements of its self-definition and self-representation are
internalised or, to some degree or another, freely endorsed by most of
its citizens – including those who belong to social strata other than
the ruling or privileged groups.
The Contest over Hegemony
Thus, a war of position is resistance to domination with culture, rather than physical might, as its foundation.
2
It is interesting to note that in the First Notebook, Gramsci says
“Gandhi’s passive resistance is a war of position” (Gramsci 1992: 219).
For Gramsci, issues of culture are what lie at the heart of any
revolutionary project; culture is “how class is lived”, it shapes how
people see their world and how they manoeuvre within it and, more
importantly, “it shapes their ability to imagine how it might be
changed, and whether they see such changes as feasible or desirable”
(Crehan 2002: 71). Gramsci’s question was: “how might a more equitable
and just order be brought about, and what is it about how people live
and imagine their lives in particular times and places that advances or
hampers progress to this more equitable and just order” (ibid: 71).
Consequently, it was his view that “one should refrain from facile
rhetoric about direct attacks against the State and concentrate instead
on the difficult and immensely complicated tasks that a ‘war of
position’ within civil society entails” (Buttigieg 2005: 41).
As Raymond Williams has argued, our account of hegemony must be a
complex one which “allows for its elements of real and constant change.
We have to emphasise that hegemony is not singular; that its own
internal structures are highly complex, and have continually to be
renewed, recreated and defended; and by the same token, that they can be
continually challenged and in certain respects modified” (Williams
1973: 37-38). Gramsci thus rejects a major deterministic-reductionist
trend within Marxism. Many Marxists tend to view civil society, purely
in an instrumentalist manner, as the hand-maiden of the ruling classes,
as the legitimiser of class divisions under capitalism. Especially over
the last two decades, in the recent period of intensified globalisation
of the Indian economy, this view has gained great strength within the
left.
3 But any historical account, which makes out that the
course of history is completely determined by the will and stratagems of
the ruling class, always leaves something to be desired. Unfortunately,
this is characteristic of much of the history in the Marxist tradition,
invariably laced also with heavy-handed certainties
4. As
Foucault has remarked, “the order imposed by such functionalist or
systematising thought is designed to mask the ruptural effects of
conflict and struggle” (Gordon 1980: 82). Our conception of the
relationship of power needs to be “simultaneously anti-structuralist and
anti-voluntarist (opposed to the assumption of a unitary, rational,
free-willed, autonomous subject)” (Jessop 1982: 254). As Foucault says,
“power relations are both intentional and non-subjective” (1978: 94).
And their reproduction is never univocal for “they define innumerable
points of confrontation, focuses of instability, each of which has its
own risks of conflict, of struggles, and of an at least temporary
inversion” (Foucault 1977: 27). As Bourdieu (1977: 179) argues, it is
imperative that “the analysis holds together what holds together in
practice, the double reality of intrinsically equivocal, ambiguous
conduct”. We entirely concur, therefore, with the critique Nicos
Mouzelis (1980: 184) offers of reductionism in Marxist theory:
Insofar as they suggest that it is possible to systematically derive
political practices and institutional structures from the “laws” or
functional requirements of the capitalist mode of production or the
machinations of an all powerful bourgeoisie, they discourage serious
study of the complicated and more or less indirect linkages between the
economic and the political instances. Moreover, in as far as they
portray collective agents as omnipotent, anthropomorphic entities or, at
the other extreme, as mere “effects” of structural determinations, they
lead either to an ultra-voluntarism or to a structural determinism –
both extremes emasculating Marxism’s dialectical character, i e, its
portrayal of collective agents in a constantly changing relation with a
social environment which both constructs actors and presents them with a
more or less large number of alternatives.
Thus, we believe Gramsci’s is a powerful contribution to our
understanding of capitalist democracies. For, it alerts us to the fact
that the very attempt at reinforcing legitimacy opens up the possibility
of its subversion. This is the constant tension of maintaining
positions of power in an avowedly democratic class society. Our
difference with Gramsci is in a fundamental disagreement with the
Marxist notion of Revolution – the notion of insurrection or overthrow,
as if what will emerge from the rubble, like magic, would be a
transformed social order. We need to give up this antediluvian, unitary
and insurrectionist conception of Revolution (with a capital R). For
many reasons. The unique appeal of “scientific socialism” was its claim
to have discovered the “laws of motion of society” that predicted the
inexorable coming of a new dawn. This teleology has ended up becoming
the chief weakness of Marxism. If change continues to be visualised in
these terms, means-ends questions will be run roughshod over and horrors
of the Stalinist kind will continue to be perpetrated. A one-track,
single-event notion of revolution must also be discarded because it
leads to the complete neglect of crucial nitty-gritty detail that forms
the heart of the transformation we dream of. It is this dry spadework
that also contains solutions to immediate distress. Running mid-day
meals in schools under active supervision of mothers, local people
managing sanitation and drinking water systems, social audits in vibrant
gram sabhas, participatory planning for watershed works, women leading
federations of SHGs and workers running industrially safe, non-polluting
factories as participant shareholders – all these and many more are the
immediate, unfinished, feasible tasks of an ongoing struggle for
change.
Unfortunately, many activists typically push these questions into a
hazy future, to be all answered after the revolution, so to speak. One
of the greatest weaknesses of the socialist project in the 20th century
was its failure to flesh out the details of possible alternatives to a
capitalist society. These are difficult questions that necessitate
intricate answers. And we need to begin looking for these here and now,
in the living laboratories of learning of our farms and factories,
villages and slums; not in some imaginary distant future after a
fictitious insurrection. Thus, civil society need not be merely the site
for the reproduction of relations of power as argued by the left; it
could also well be the locus of serious challenges to the dominant
discourse and practices, charting the pathway to an alternative world.
We asked two questions at the beginning of this article: Can civil
society be seen as an agent of social transformation in India today? In
what form, under what circumstances can the answer to this question be
given in the affirmative? Having laid out a theoretical framework to
answer these questions, before we go on to propose a typology of civil
society action, we need to recognise the specific historical context
within which we are located. Scholars have long recognised the tension
between capitalism and democracy (Radford 2013; Varshney 2013a, 2013b).
But there is something very specific about the Indian context of this
tension. As Varshney has argued, universal franchise, the right to vote
without any distinction of gender, race, ethnicity or income, “came to
the West after the Industrial Revolution – that is, after incomes had
reached a substantially high level. India was to practice it at a very
low level of income” (Varshney 2013a: 3), immediately after independence
from colonial rule. It is also true that although many postcolonial
nations took the democratic pledge, a very large number had abandoned it
already by the 1960s (Huntington 1991). Varshney does not exaggerate
when he claims for India that it is “for the first time in human
history, a poor nation has practiced universal franchise for so long”
(op cit: 4). It is also a fact that unlike in the west, in India the
poor vote more than the rich. Thus, the pressure on the democratic state
to respond to the demands of those who may not automatically benefit
from the growth process generated by the capitalist system, the
imperatives of legitimation we alluded to earlier, have been even more
acute in the Indian context, especially as the decades have rolled by
after Independence. We need to bear this in mind as we examine the
typology of civil society action offered below.
Empirical Strands within Civil Society in India
We propose to divide civil society action in India today into four broad types.
5
Each of these types comes with their own distinct motivations,
strategies and inclinations. And each, we believe, has very different
implications for carrying forward an agenda of social transformation.
Beyond the typology we propose there are, of course, also caste and
religious associations, proselytising non-governmental organisations
(NGOs) or specific interest groups like trade unions, industry lobbies
such as the Federation of Indian Chambers of Commerce and Industry
(FICCI) or the Confederation of Indian Industry (CII), as also the media
and academia. There are think tanks that are specifically dedicated to
reinforcing or questioning the structures of power. Their role, in
intellectual terms, is relatively straightforward to understand and
these need not detain us here. We are leaving these out in our typology
and will only concentrate upon those segments within civil society that
claim to be acting in the larger public interest, as also those who seek
to bring about social transformation. Many of these are relatively
unacknowledged in the public imagination, as they operate away from the
glare of media publicity, in spaces among the subalterns, which for
Partha Chatterjee do not even constitute proper civil society, but for
us offer the most powerful examples of the same.
Type A: Compassion and Charity: Within our typology, the
oldest form of civil society action is the one that arises from the
well-springs of compassion and charity. This is the kind of work done by
organisations and individuals who distribute blankets to the homeless
in winter, run open kitchens for the hungry, are devoted to prevention
of cruelty to animals, look after the differently-abled and the elderly
and devote themselves to the care of the terminally ill. The aim is to
reach out and provide immediate relief and succour to those in distress.
The idea is not to redress long-term causes of this suffering; it is
only to provide pain amelioration.
Type B: Developmental NGOs: Our second type of civil society
action tries to go a little further by recognising that much of this
distress is a consequence of the twin failures of markets and
government. In a society characterised by mass poverty and high
inequality, market failure is rampant. Throughout the world, public
goods like health, education and environment have been invariably
provided for or protected by governments. Ever since the Great
Depression of the 1930s, capitalist democracies have seen major
investments by the state in the fundamental rights of its citizenry.
Large investments in infrastructure have also been the domain of the
public sector in newly independent countries. Unfortunately, however, in
India, both the magnitude of this effort and its quality have left much
to be desired. Thus, the suffering of our people is not just a tale of
market failure, it is also a failure of governance.
Much civil society action in India can, thus, be seen as an effort to
bridge the gap left by this dual failure of markets and government.
Many large NGOs occupy this space. They run schools, hospitals,
watershed programmes and are engaged in a wide range of basic service
delivery. The difficulty here is that these NGOs seek almost to act as
substitutes, parallel to the state (sometimes even referred to as
chhoti sarkar),
even as they generally remain confined to “oases of excellence”.
Indeed, as they attempt to grow larger they become subject to phenomena
similar to government failure, as scale becomes the enemy of quality.
But, of course, the problem with such action is much deeper as it
ultimately reinforces passive dependence of citizens upon the NGO, quite
akin to what government welfare programmes have tended to do. Without,
and this is most important, being subject to the accountability that an
elected government has to face.
Type C: Rights-based Activism: Taking a much more critical
view of the “system” is civil society action of the third type in our
classification. This is work based on providing a critique of mainstream
practices of governments and markets and generating wider awareness of
this critical view. The aim often is empowerment of citizens by making
them aware of their rights under the Constitution. In theoretical terms,
a lot of this activity could be said to be inspired by Amartya Sen’s
pioneering work on agency, rights and capabilities and in historical
terms can be seen to date from the period Sen initiated this work across
the globe (Nussbaum 1997).
While Type C civil society action is always interrogative and
oppositional in nature, its more extreme form is animated at times by
the conviction that the system is intrinsically irremediable and needs
overthrow. This could be described as counter-hegemony in the classical
Gramscian sense, based on an insurrectionist vision of social
transformation and has a much older, radical Marxist legacy in India.
This kind of action is inspired by the notion that it is the “false
consciousness” of the masses that leads to their tolerance of what is
dished out to them, when actually there is no hope for them within the
system as it exists, with all its inequities and injustices. The risk
for such groups has been that they end up remaining marginal voices on
the fringe, which may or may not have an impact on the way the
mainstream functions. There is a fundamentalism in the world view of
their leaders that rejects any engagement with the system as an
unacceptable compromise and any kind of relief (Type A) or developmental
work (Type B) as something that “blunts the edge of class
contradictions”. Invariably, therefore, the time frame that the leaders
of this kind of action set for themselves is often at variance from that
of those they lead, the ones who suffer most from the consequences of
being at the receiving end of the injustices of the system. Even when
such action is not motivated by insurrectionist zeal, it tends to be
based on a fundamentalism of positions that is generally averse to
compromise, whether on specific development projects or proposed
legislations.
Type D: Engaging the State and Leveraging the Market: The most
recent and, in our view, most creative and effective type of civil
society action in India belongs to Type D. This kind of action accepts
the critique proffered by Type C activists and fights for rights of
citizens. But it believes that change is best fostered by deep
engagement with the state in a constructive manner within time frames
that are more sensitive to the needs of the people in whose name this
action takes place. Thus, there is a basic difference in the attitude
towards the state. It is recognised that, with all its flaws, the state
in India remains potentially a protector of the marginalised. But for
that the state needs to function in a much more accountable and
transparent manner. The goal, therefore, is to suitably transform the
state, its policies and its functioning in order that it can play this
role.
6 But the vision goes beyond viewing it as a welfare
state. The goal is to enshrine rights that the state is obliged to
fulfil and to compel it to do so and to also design more effective ways
in which these rights can be realised on the ground. There is also less
fundamentalism and more openness to compromise in recognition of the
urgency for change. The “problematique of representation” is taken
rather more seriously than in Type C.
The best example of Type D civil society action is provided by the
work of the Mazdoor Kisan Shakti Sangathan (MKSS), which has over the
past decade evolved from Type C to Type D.
7 Having worked in
the 1990s on the fringes in rural Rajasthan on the right to information
and the rights of rural workers to basic entitlements, the MKSS moved
into a radically more intense engagement with the state after the coming
to power of the United Progressive Alliance (UPA) government in 2004.
This has not only meant actively working with the state to enact
pro-poor legislations and programmes but even becoming part of the
Directorate of Social Audit in the Government of Andhra Pradesh to
ensure that what is enacted on paper is implemented effectively on the
ground. It must be remembered that the UPA was unexpectedly voted into
power after the people of the country resoundingly rejected the “India
Shining” slogan of the ruling dispensation of the time. There was then
intense pressure on the UPA to respond effectively to Verdict 2004. This
opened up huge possibilities of civil society engagement with the state
on issues of concern to the
aam aadmi. This set the scene for
the subsequent enactment of historic pieces of legislation such as the
Right to Information Act,National Rural Employment Guarantee Act (NREGA)
and FRA under UPA-I. It is widely acknowledged that inputs from civil
society organisations such as MKSS, the Campaign for Survival and
Dignity and many others played a major role in fleshing out these laws.
Similarly, under UPA-II, the Right to Education (RTE) Act and the
National Food Security Act (NFSA) have benefited from significant civil
society inputs.
Type D action also includes those who pay attention to crafting
alternatives to mainstream development (as in Type B) but this is sought
to be done not in pristine NGO isolation but in deep engagement with
the state and through leveraging the power of the market in a way that
can benefit the marginalised. Organisations like the National Consortium
of Civil Society Organisations on MGNREGA have involved themselves in
developing partnerships with gram panchayats (GPs) and state and central
governments to build state capacities for more effective implementation
of the NREGA. Thus, unlike Type B civil society action, here the
implementation remains firmly the responsibility of GPs and state
governments but civil society plays a supportive capacity building and
hand-holding role. Great hope is invested in the possibilities of
genuine grass-roots democracy opened up by the 73rd and 74th amendments
to the Constitution and the potential empowerment of local
self-government. The framework is one of partnerships, with each partner
playing their designated role. The vision is also of “cascading
redundancy” (SPS 2010), with civil society becoming gradually redundant
in more and more respects, as GPs become stronger, capacities of
frontline functionaries of the state expand and thousands of “barefoot”
community resource persons get empowered. In her study of the work of
Samaj Pragati Sahayog (SPS), Chhotray (2007) describes this stance as
one of “working the state”. The possibilities of leveraging state
resources have expanded in an unprecedented manner following the UPA’s
rise to power. During the Eleventh Plan period, the UPA government spent
upwards of Rs 7,00,000 crore on its major flagship programmes of social
and economic inclusion. The corresponding annual figure in the Twelfth
Plan is Rs 2,00,000 crore (Planning Commission 2012). The goal of Type D
civil society action is to try and ensure that these massive outlays
genuinely translate into enduring outcomes on the ground for the people
for whom this money is meant. The overall perspective animating such
action is that it is no longer useful, in the manner of the left, to
merely keep reiterating the importance of the public sector in the
Indian economy. Rather, it is regarded as much more urgent to work out
ways in which the public sector, especially in its flagship programme
avatar, could be reformed by making it much more accountable to and
effective in meeting the needs of the most marginalised.
Finally, Type D civil society action has recently also included
engagement with markets. The traditional Gandhian notion of independent,
self-sufficient village communities is rejected as a romantic utopia.
What is recognised, however, is that the participation of small and
marginal farmers as isolated individuals in the marketplace has been a
source of great exploitation and injustice for them. The idea,
therefore, is to build powerful corporate institutions of the poor, led
by women, who would be able to better compete in the market on the basis
of their collective economic power. These include federations of
women’s SHGs and producer companies. This kind of work, although still
in its infancy, has already shown great promise in lifting the poorest
people of our country out of poverty as they come to the market as both
powerful producers and consumers. Banks in remote rural areas of India
have begun to see their own enlightened self-interest in doing business
with these strong institutions of the poor, who also are an effective
check on the predatory activities of exploitative microfinance
institutions. There are instances of balance sheets of loss-making banks
being turned around, thanks to the impeccable repayment record of SHGs
and their federations. Type D civil society action has pushed the
government to make policy changes to facilitate and support the economic
activities of such farmer producer organisations. There are also
examples of these institutions of the poor providing a major check on
corruption in government systems and ensuring greater accountability and
better service delivery under government programmes through the
pressure exerted by their collective action.
8 Indeed, in our
view, the very survival of Indian democracy, in the face of severe
distress suffered by people over the last two decades, marked by
farmers’ suicides and Maoist violence, could be said to owe in no small
measure to Type D civil society action.
Conclusions
In order to gain legitimacy in the eyes of the people they govern,
capitalist democracies are compelled to open up spaces that need to be
utilised with a renewed creativity by those fighting for a more equal,
less exploitative social order. We need courage and imagination to go
beyond the stolid certainties of a teleological science of history.
These spaces – such as the 73rd amendment empowering local bodies of
self-governance or NREGA – provide glimmers of hope for a new
participatory democracy. Of course, at the same time, it is also true
that we cannot take the existence of a space for civil society action
for granted. There are repeated instances of violence by powerful vested
interests within society and of the state taking on a more draconian
character and showing its repressive face. Whether it is RTI or NREGA
social audit activists or those questioning destructive forms of
development and/or asserting their right over natural resources, they
all face a relentless barrage of violence.
9 Therefore, it is
imperative that we do not take this space for granted. We must also not
become cynical and despair but both value this space and fight for it to
remain and expand. And this demands a truly innovative brand of
politics. Not one of mere challenge and confrontation; but one that
includes nitty-gritty work to build fresh cadres and alternative
institutions for a participatory social order. Where democracy, equality
and development are not just demanded, they are also constructively
built at the grass roots.
For civil society organisations to be a positive source of change in
this direction they need to satisfy some basic pre-conditions in their
own internal functioning. Apart from high degrees of competence and
professionalism, they need to demonstrate inner democracy, transparency
and external accountability in their functioning. For those holding up a
mirror to state and society need to subject themselves to the very
highest standards in each of these respects. They also need to engage in
building partnerships of mutual respect, in humble acknowledgement of
their own finitude, with local communities, PRIs, academia, media,
markets and the state. And, above all, they also need a vision for their
own future. And that future has to be one of “cascading redundancy”,
where the idea is to make oneself redundant in more and more respects
over time. The goal has to be one of people’s empowerment and building
stronger institutions of participatory democracy at the grass roots. As
these institutions gain in strength, the nature of civil society support
changes, evolves and the need for it declines over time. Such civil
society action, in our reckoning, would build a more inclusive society
and a stronger Indian democracy. This is the kind of civil society
action that has the potential to become a powerful force for social
transformation in 21st century India.